Type | Working Paper - Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UCD |
Title | Agricultural productivity growth in China: farm level versus national measurement |
Author(s) | |
Publication (Day/Month/Year) | 1999 |
URL | http://escholarship.org/uc/item/51j0k8kv.pdf |
Abstract | It is generally accepted that the rapid output growth in China’s agriculture from 1979 to 1984 was due to significant productivity gain.1 In most developing countries such as China, agricultural productivity gains are central to the growth of national wealth, enabling the diversion of agricultural labor into producing non-agricultural products, leading to higher real per capita incomes.2 The continuation of agricultural productivity growth in China is particularly important, as more than 300 million workers remain in agriculture (nearly 50 percent of the country’s total labor force).3 An increase in rural incomes, through further agricultural productivity gains, would not only help close the urban-rural income gap, 4 but it would also serve as an important source of national economic growth. The coastal-centered economic boom has recently slowed down and the ongoing reform of China’s state owned enterprises has resulted in 150 million unemployed city residents.5 This means that policy will continue to discourage labor movement from the countryside to the cities and therefore the rural economy itself will be viewed as a key to future national economic growth. Not only is labor an abundant resource in rural China, but a large percentage of the labor force is also used in grain production. However, grain cultivation is a relatively low-return activity, and the marginal labor productivity in grain is thought to be low. Further economic reforms in the countryside would encourage farmers to withdraw from grain in favor of other forms of crops or activities. However, major agricultural reforms are on the back burner. From 1998, the central government reasserted its emphasis on "grain self-sufficiency" and introduced renewed government control over grain prices, by prohibiting private agents in the grain market.6 According to national aggregate data, total factor productivity (TFP) in China’s agriculture increased by 55 percent from 1979 to 1984.7 This was unprecedented in the developing world, and most of the rapid change was attributed to the Household Responsibility System (HRS), which was a one-off institutional change.8 After the effects of the HRS peteredout, a policy issue that surfaced in the late 1980s and early 1990s was a slowdown in the growth of investment in agriculture.9 Despite this apparent investment slowdown, we find, in this paper, that the national data indicate there have been tremendous productivity gains in China in the 1990s. The TFPI increased by 47 percent from 1990 to 1996, according to the national aggregate statistics, and using Wen’s methodology. Is this large agricultural productivity gain in the 1990s plausible? Perhaps the answer is no, because recent concerns over the reliability of national production statistics calls into question the accuracy of the national productivity index.10 The purpose of this paper is to measure post-reform agricultural productivity growth in China using farm level (i.e., household) data and compare the results to national data, for the 1978 to 1996 time period. Measuring productivity growth is a complicated task, even in western economies where data are much better than is the case for China. Previous studies of China’s agricultural growth have all used very aggregate national or provincial data, even though the theory is based on microeconomic decision-making relationships at the individual farm level. Our disaggregate household level data are unique and they were obtained from farm cost surveys in Jiangsu Province, one of the most progressive agricultural provinces in China. |
» | China - National Population Census 1990 |